Cryptocurrency and the Problem of Intermediation
Apr30
Journal Article8

Cryptocurrency and the Problem of Intermediation

Independent Review, 20(4): 569-588.

Abstract. The volatility of Bitcoin has caused many to dismiss its potential. Bitcoin is, however, very similar to another money commodity with an essentially rigid supply that saw much greater historical success: gold. The paper considers the factors that allowed currencies on the gold standard to adjust their short-run nominal supply in response to velocity shocks, in particular fractional reserve banking. The benefits and the hurdles of establishing financial intermediation in crypto-currency are considered, as well as the possibility of managing the money supply to create a macroeconomically stable crypto-currency without the need for intermediation at all. Such schemes ultimately require an existing market of intermediaries in order to provide any benefits, the emergence of which governments are for the moment well-positioned to prevent.

This paper assumes a working knowledge of monetarism and unfamiliarity with Bitcoin. For a summary which assumes a working knowledge of Bitcoin and unfamiliarity with monetarism, see the article on Coindesk “How ‘Bitbanks’ Could Solve Bitcoin’s Volatility Problem”.

The rise of cryptocurrency in the past decade is more than simply a technological feat; it is a real-world incarnation of a monetary system with numerous features that have existed to date only as thought experiments. As with any unprecedented innovation, bold claims are made for it. The boldest, perhaps, is the claim that cryptocurrency in general, or Bitcoin in particular, can or will supplant the current international regime of central bank issued monies.

The claim has some plausibility. Distributed technologies such as Uber or Airbnb are already rendering obsolete many established regulatory regimes, much to the benefit of consumers. Because cryptocurrencies lack a central issuer, the hope is that they too will be able to grow outside of established regulatory structures until they become too big to ignore. Of course, the challenger faces a number of daunting hurdles before this goal becomes feasible. Existing regulatory structures are not totally avoidable. In addition to the opposition it faces and will continue to face from established interests, Bitcoin also must overcome a number of technical and economic hurdles.

Bitcoin’s purchasing power volatility, on the order of history’s most severe episodes of hyperinflation, is emblematic of these latter hurdles. In contrast to the narrow focus on stabilization that has characterized much of the literature thus far, this paper considers the institutional prerequisites of purchasing power stability, economic efficiency, and sustained economic growth – namely, a market for financial intermediation. It is such a market that cryptocurrency entrepreneurs will find most difficult to operate outside existing regulatory regimes.

After a brief introduction to the mechanism of cryptocurrency, this paper compares its development over the past several years to the development of fractional-reserve banking under a regime of gold redeemability. From there, drawing on the historical experience of gold, it explores the technical, legal, and economic hurdles cryptocurrencies face in the future, focusing on the unique problems of financial intermediation in these currencies. Although cryptocurrencies have already established a niche for themselves as media of exchange, these hurdles will need to be overcome before cryptocurrencies can be competitive with – much less supplant – central bank issues.

Finally, the paper evaluates some schemes to stabilize purchasing power by automatically adjusting the quantity of coins, and concludes that the future progress of Bitcoin, and of cryptocurrency more generally, depends not only on the achievement of a more or less stable purchasing power, but also on the establishment of financial intermediaries whose cryptocurrency-denominated liabilities circulate as media of exchange. Although stability is certainly necessary to support a modern industrial economy, it is hardly sufficient: to achieve demand elasticity for a currency outside of a market of financial intermediaries is no foundation for economic growth and efficiency. Without such a market, Bitcoin remains in a sense “dependent” on other currencies such as the dollar.

What Is Cryptocurrency?

A cryptocurrency is a method of constituting virtual “coins”, and providing for their secure ownership and transaction using a cryptographic problem. This problem is designed to be easy to verify, but computationally difficult to arrive at a solution. Various cryptocurrencies use different functions for this purpose, the most common being a hash target, by which hashes are calculated so as to come in below a certain value.1 The hash target (i.e. the difficulty of the problem) is adjusted every so often based on the total computing power on the network, which has the advantage of keeping the time between solutions more or less constant. Other protocols, such as Primecoin, provide for the problem by the calculation of large prime numbers. In theory any hard-to-calculate but easy-to-verify function with easily adjustable difficulty would do.

This computationally intensive “proof of work” is the method by which transactions are verified as unique and trustworthy. To incentivize participation, transactors can include a transaction fee which goes to the first user to successfully verify it. This fee is optional in Bitcoin, but mandatory in some others.

In addition, verifiers are rewarded by the network with a certain number of coins after successfully verifying a block of transactions. This process, called mining, is the means by which the supply of coins on a network is expanded, and the adjustable difficulty ensures that computing advances will not affect the rate of expansion. As might be expected, the marginal cost of mining (mainly electricity) tends to equilibrate to the marginal benefit.2 In Bitcoin’s case, the reward for mining halves every 210,000 blocks verified, leading to a supply path over time with a positive first derivative that diminishes discontinuously to zero.3 A great variety of supply schemes have been implemented by alternative cryptocurrencies, some of which are discussed in subsequent sections.

A coin itself is constituted by its transaction history on the network, going back to the block from which it was mined. Each input into a transaction points to the output of a previous transaction. This history is kept track of by every computer on the network in a continuously updating record called the blockchain – literally, a chain of transaction blocks to which newly verified blocks are added. Because transaction records are public, anonymity is maintained only by keeping the account owners private. If there are competing blockchains among different users – for example if two transactions are received in a different order by different users, or if someone attempts to forge a transaction – the protocol defines rules by which only one is accepted. This method is quite secure, the more so as the protocol gains wider currency. Bitcoin and its close relatives will prefer the longest blockchain – that is, the one with the most computing power behind it. Thus, to forge a transaction, an attacker would have to make sure that his own blockchain was longer than the legitimate one, requiring him to have at his disposal more computing power than the total of the honest nodes.4

Here we may briefly put to rest several recurring fears surrounding cryptocurrencies. First, the proliferation of copycat currencies (“altcoins”) cannot be inflationary unless any protocol is a perfect substitute for any other.5 Whether or not they are substitutable in some technical sense, entrenched network benefits mean that copycat protocols will not displace or rival existing protocols without clear feature advantages. Where physical notes from one bank or another may fit equally well in a wallet (and might even both be dollars), holding multiple cryptocurrencies involves the technical inconvenience of operating on multiple disjunct protocols, plus the additional calculational inconvenience that the currencies float against one another in value.6

Second, though the protocol is indeed defined arbitrarily in software, it cannot be changed arbitrarily once created. Once a protocol comes into use, the control of its constitution depends entirely on continued trust in the developers. Each user must be persuaded to upgrade. Thus, contra Grinberg (2012), the fact that “most users would use [a] new version of the software because of their trust in the development team” does not make the development team “the de facto central bank of Bitcoin”. “Bank of issue”, in fact, would be a broader category (private, non-central banks have also issued currency throughout history), a safer claim, and still wrong. The power of a bank of issue consists in its ability to issue new currency indistinguishable from (or in the case of a central bank, with the same legal tender status as) the old, and hence to gather seigniorage. The Bitcoin development team has no such power.7 Given the precedent of open-source cryptocurrency protocols, trust in the developers is reasonably attributed to their continuing trustworthiness: a malicious update will be easily spotted and ignored.

The Moneyness of Cryptocurrency

What makes cryptocurrency money? Mises’ regression theorem (1996, pp. 408ff) explaining the emergence of money, by which a particular commodity gradually overcomes network hurdles and becomes accepted as money by virtue of its increasing liquidity, has lately been taken by some armchair Austrians to imply that cryptocurrency cannot be money, because it was never accepted as something useful of its own account. This is a curious argument, considering Mises saw money as a category of human action. In other words, something is money when people use it as money – that is, as a medium of indirect exchange. And in this sense, cryptocurrency clearly qualifies. The regression theorem begins with the fact of a money and reconstructs the history by which it became such. It cannot be used in the other direction, starting with the observed history of a commodity and passing judgment on its moneyness.

If the theorem is interpreted strictly so as to demand some non-monetary starting point to give it its original positive value, we could say that Bitcoin’s innovativeness or anti-authoritarian ethos was a consumption good for its initial adopters (White [2014] calls this “Affinity demand”). It would be less of a stretch, however, to say that non-monetary (industrial) use is a possible (and so far the most historically significant) starting point, but not the only conceivable one. It would be foolish to try to enumerate an exhaustive list of the ways a commodity, even an inconvertible one, might initially gain wide enough acceptance to function as money. History, in this case, rules out an interpretation that denies to cryptocurrencies the possibility of being money.

As for why cryptocurrencies might be used as money, it is easy to see how they fit the textbook qualities of a useful commodity for indirect exchange:

  1. Portability. Cryptocurrencies excel here because they have no extension in physical space. They can be exchanged using any device on which you can carry your “wallet file”, and it is no more difficult to send an amount across the world than across the street.
  2. Durability. Though coins can be “lost”, they will not get worn out or depreciate.
  3. Divisibility. Bitcoins are divisible to eight decimal places. In principle there is no technical limit to the divisibility a protocol might allow.
  4. Security. As noted earlier, protocol-level theft and counterfeiting is extremely difficult, though – obviously – the protocol has no special way to prevent more traditional types of theft and fraud such as social engineering.

In addition to these “intrinsic” characteristics, money commodities will tend to possess some economic characteristics as well, such as liquidity (ready acceptance), saleability (wide acceptance), and stability of value. It is on these points, rather than the first four, that cryptocurrencies have borne the most criticism.

On acceptance, though Bitcoins cannot yet be spent at the grocery store, a significant and increasing number of online merchants do accept them, and they have already broken into the physical world with the advent of Bitcoin ATM kiosks in various large cities in Canada and the U.S. A vibrant and growing niche ensures that Bitcoins remain quite liquid. With large Bitcoin exchanges accessible online, Bitcoins can be bought and sold nearly instantly at the market exchange rate from anywhere with internet access.

On stability of value, however, cryptocurrencies reveal their inadequacy as day-to-day currency. That mass adoption of cryptocurrencies has not been forthcoming cannot be attributed (as Luther [2013] argues) primarily to network effects. Perhaps this will be a relevant bottleneck in the future. For now, though, the primary impediment is purchasing power volatility. Bitcoin, for example, despite making up 86% of the entire cryptocurrency market (White 2014), has suffered from frequent and severe jumps and crashes since its inception in 2010, as shown in Figure 1.

volatility

Figure 1. Daily percent change in the Bitcoin-Dollar exchange rate, 2010-2016.
Data is from the largest exchange at each point in time, so the collapse of one exchange (e.g. Mt. Gox
in February 2014) does not introduce spurious volatility.

The daily change in the USD/BTC exchange rate has reached nearly 50% in both directions, and regularly exceeds 10%. By contrast, the daily change in the USD/EUR exchange rate over the same period never exceeded 2.5% in either direction. This is not simply a problem of scale which can be expected to diminish as the volume of transactions grows: with the exception of its extreme volatility during its time beneath a dollar per bitcoin (roughly the left quarter of figure 1), there is no notable correlation between volatility, price, or volume of transactions following its rise past about $10, even up past $1,000.

Milton Friedman (1951, p. 207) characterized the countercyclical effects of a pure commodity currency (i.e. a system, like the Bitcoin ecosystem currently, in which base money forms the entire money stock) as depending primarily on an elastic supply of the money commodity. The supply of Bitcoins, however, is very nearly invariant to anything except time.8 In terms of the equation of exchange MV=PT,9 M is perfectly exogenous and predictable. Having no outlet in the money supply, then, changes in the demand for cash balances must affect nominal spending until prices adjust.

In addition to a secular upward trend as the ecosystem grows (hence the much-lamented “deflationary” aspect of Bitcoin), the demand for Bitcoins is also highly volatile. Though difficult to measure, it is well accepted that a very large portion of all Bitcoin transactions are made for speculative purposes – up to 90% by some estimates. While it is true that investment spending is inherently more volatile than consumption spending, the more important factor is that without a credible anchor for expectations of the currency’s value, demand shocks will be self-reinforcing. Frankel and Rose (1995) describe the mechanism:

Expectations can be described as stabilizing when the effect of an appreciation today – relative to some long-run path or mean – is to induce market participants to forecast depreciation in the future. . . . Expectations can be described as destabilizing, on the other hand, when the effect of an appreciation is to induce market participants to forecast more appreciation in the future.

For currencies with a credible price anchor – which does not necessarily imply a fixed exchange rate10 – speculation will tend to be a stabilizing force, pushing the actual value back toward that target. However, without such an anchor, “the variability of exchanges will tend to multiply its magnitude and may turn what originally might have been a minor inconvenience into a major disturbance” (Hayek 1937, p. 64). More prescient words could hardly have been spoken of Bitcoin’s current situation.

For this reason, Bitcoin is by no means a unit of account,11 a situation that bears a striking resemblance to episodes of hyperinflation. Eichengreen (1994, p. 135), for example, quotes Schacht’s (1927) account of the German hyperinflation, noting that merchants “calculated prices with reference to the exchange rate and converted mark receipts into foreign currency as quickly as possible.” Because prices become nearly perfectly flexible, hyperinflations are remarkable as the most consistent example of short-run purchasing power parity (Rogoff 1996). Much the same occurs with Bitcoin today, and with even less friction. Merchants can convert their dollar prices into bitcoin using up-to-the-second data feeds, and services like Bitpay allow immediate exchange for local currency following a transaction, minimizing the risk to the merchant of holding a balance of bitcoins (Luther and White 2014).

Though Bitcoin is far from hyperinflationary, evidently the safety valves that spare the volume of transactions much of the brunt of fluctuations in the exchange rate come into operation in response to any sufficiently violent and sustained purchasing power or exchange rate paroxysms. Should merchants begin to adopt Bitcoin as a unit of account, however (let us suppose there is a long enough quiet period of relative stability for this to happen), prices will not be able to adjust as quickly to changes in nominal spending, and the familiar output effects of monetary disturbances will manifest themselves. The extant crop of cryptocurrencies, then, will hardly be able to supplant the currencies on which they depend as an anchor for the speedy adjustment of prices.

Bitcoin and Gold

Nevertheless, a fixed supply in the face of shifting demand is no death knell for cryptocurrency. It will be illuminating to consider the historical development of another successful money commodity with a mostly exogenous global supply: gold.12 To answer how Bitcoin and other cryptocurrencies with a rigidly capped nominal supply might overcome the problems associated with it, we ask then: how did gold (and other metals) overcome these problems?

Before the explosion of economic growth in the West, a pure commodity standard prevailed: the medium of exchange was actual metal coins. The global money supply was therefore more or less fixed in the short run.13 Without well-integrated international markets, money prices did not vary much from day to day in normal circumstances. Economic growth was slow and mining not all that productive, so “natural” inflation and deflation occurred over very long periods when they occurred at all. Even the so-called Price Revolution, during which prices in Europe more than doubled following the discovery and importation of New World silver and gold, took place over such a long period that the annualized inflation rate stayed in the low-by-modern-standards range of 1 to 1.5% (Kugler and Bernholz 2007). In short, rigidity of the supply of precious metals did not pose a serious problem.

Fortunately, the advent of sustained economic growth starting with the industrial revolution was accompanied by a banking revolution as well. Moneylending lost its stigma, and with financial and actuarial innovations, trade and industry were able to flourish. The observation that financial development generally precedes industrialization can, at least for this era, be explained by the happy circumstance that these financial innovations – fractional reserve banking in particular – were able to overcome gold’s nominal supply problem. As Mises (1953, p. 298f) noted of the time period,

The development of the clearing system and of fiduciary media [i.e. circulating bank liabilities] has at least kept pace with the potential increase of the demand for money brought about by the extension of the money economy, so that the tremendous increase in the exchange value of money, which otherwise would have occurred as a consequence of the extension of the use of money, has been completely avoided.

Rather than affecting prices in the long run and the volume of transactions in the meantime, changes in the demand for cash balances, which were for the first time rapidly growing, could be accommodated by changes in the money supply. By using loans and credit to pyramid a larger and variable stock of banknotes and deposits on top of a smaller and fixed supply of physical gold, the money supply was, to varying extents across different countries, able to roughly stabilize nominal spending even in the face of wide variations in the demand for money.14

We might expect similar financial innovations to precede an explosion in the use of cryptocurrencies. They face, however, a number of unique hurdles for which the history of gold provides little guidance.

Technical Hurdles

At this point it will be useful to distinguish the currency itself from its method of exchange. For most of the world’s monetary history, the method of exchange was generally hand-to-hand. The currency transition from gold coins (base money) to paper banknotes (inside money)15 that marked the advent of fractional-reserve banking was much facilitated by the fact that the same method of exchange that was suitable for one was just as suitable for the other. The two are, of course, wholly different commodities, each entailing a different sort of claim, even if they are denominated equivalently and exchangeable one for the other at a fixed rate. But besides the usually small risk of bank collapse, accepting and spending gold-backed banknotes had no serious drawbacks compared to gold, and required no special investment to begin. Indeed, an important advantage of banknotes is that, with the same method of exchange, they were less costly (more convenient) to use than gold coins.

The more recent advent of electronic payment, in contrast, marked a transition in the method of exchange. Though a similar process had existed for centuries with checks, electronic payment no longer involved the hand-to-hand transfer of an asset (such as a check). Telephone lines and bank software were now the method of exchange. Even though the currency was the same as before (dollar-denominated deposit balances), the change in method entailed a network hurdle and a fixed cost to join the network, as merchants had to install card readers next to their cash registers. Nevertheless, the benefits were clear enough that by now most merchants have joined the network: as of 2011, credit and debit card payments constituted nearly two thirds of the retail sales volume in the U.S.

In both cases, the transition was much aided by being limited to one aspect or the other. Those deciding whether to accept a new currency faced no initial cost to joining the network, and those deciding whether to change their method of exchange did not have to worry about whether to accept a new currency. Cryptocurrencies had the misfortune of having to effect both transitions at once, and on top of that, being denominated in a different unit of account!16

Bitcoin’s success in spite of this double hurdle is remarkable. But the hurdles are not all behind: the establishment of bank liabilities redeemable in cryptocurrency will again have to make both transitions at once. The necessity of a currency transition is implied in the establishment of fractional-reserve banking, in exactly the same way as the original transition from physical coins to bank liabilities. The essential problem here is trust. The necessity of a method transition, however, deserves a few more words. Because a cryptocurrency protocol defines both the coinage and exchange of the base money, issuing liabilities on a fractional reserve basis requires more than simply adding parameters to coins.17 A bank that wanted to vary its issue with demand would need to create its own coinage and exchange mechanism – a new protocol – which would not be compatible with the original, even if its processing took place on the same blockchain.18 Nor would one issuer’s liabilities be compatible with another’s. Merchants would need to implement the new protocol, facing a similar sort of cost to those merchants installing pads to accept credit cards.

Technical innovations can, however, collapse the two method transitions. Issuers would find it in their interest to provide an abstraction layer that allows the same apparatus to transact in both base money and banknotes. Open Transactions (OT) already facilitates secure cross-blockchain exchange of different crypto-currencies. If the issuer’s protocol can be administered on a blockchain, OT can provide a framework for the relatively transparent use of multiple inside monies and base monies, and even the issue of notes backed by and denominated in a basket of crypto-currencies.

In fact, such issues could be denominated in any unit at all. Again, credit card networks are an illuminating precedent. These perform a similar function to our abstraction layer: merchants do not have to implement separate pads to accept Visa and Master Card, because there is a network that transparently routes the transaction to the appropriate firm. Merchants can even choose which cards they are willing to accept (many refuse American Express, for example, which charges the merchant more per transaction to fund its rewards program). And the process is rendered transparent to consumers by being denominationally agnostic: each network routes dollars just as well as euros, and even automatically exchanges them, based on what the merchant takes.

Nonetheless, though an abstraction layer can lower the network costs of adopting crypto-notes, even if the transition can successfully be made, important qualities of the base money are inevitably lost by using inside money. OT can minimize the level of trust that users must have in the bank – for example, the possibility of absconding with deposits can be ruled out. But users must still trust the bank:

  1. To maintain redeemability at par, i.e. not to inflate. This possibility is the price of quantity-stabilizing intermediation. Against it there is no recourse but market competition, which would be easily subverted by the incautious application of any modern economy’s byzantine banking regulations.
  2. With their information. This exposes users to hackers or subpoenas. As Cavalcanti (2010) put it: “Although anonymity preserves money, it rules out all forms of credit.”

If minimizing the necessity of trust is integral to the cryptocurrency ethos, the banknotes of a crypto-intermediary will succeed in the market only by sacrificing those qualities to which cryptocurrencies owe their initial success.

Institutional Hurdles

In addition to the intrinsic network hurdles, regulatory uncertainty and hostility also constitute an extrinsic hurdle for intermediation in a way that they do not for the protocols themselves. Though governments around the world have targeted cryptocurrency users (often under money-laundering regulations for individuals, and financial regulations for would-be intermediaries), their success has been mixed. The protocols cannot be targeted or shut down; the best that can be done is to pinpoint prominent individual users, a drawn-out and expensive process. This is the reason that Bitcoin has not succumbed to the same fate as the Liberty Dollar (Dowd 2014), and it is precisely the protection that will vanish with the rise of financial intermediation. OT can prevent the seizure of users’ assets, but it cannot prevent the forcible closure of any intermediary that becomes large enough to attract attention.

No doubt some degree of intermediation and liability issue can survive anonymously, even under the harshest of legal climates. But legal hostility severely limits the scale of such an undertaking, scale being an important factor in the trustworthiness of an intermediary’s promise to redeem. This highlights another potential economic hurdle, the closest parallel to which might be the “free-banking” era in the United States, where legal restrictions on branch banking limited banks’ capitalization and diversification (Dowd 1992). This limitation left banks highly vulnerable to seasonal fluctuations, and made the system as a whole notoriously unstable. Should concerted legal hostility lead to a similar market structure of crypto-intermediaries, the cryptocurrency market might well become even more unstable than it is at present.

Finally, should a cryptocurrency come to serve primarily as a reserve currency on top of which circulating liabilities are pyramided, the centralization of transactions that would accompany this development increases the risk of protocol fraud. As noted earlier, the protocol’s security lies in the assumption that an attacker will never be able to out-work all the honest computers on the network. The use of bank liabilities as media of exchange has the effect of taking people off the original network and putting them on the bank’s own services. If the majority of computing power on the base currency’s protocol comes to be controlled by a few banks, the generation of a fraudulent blockchain would require only the hijacking of the servers of a few major intermediaries, or collusion among them.

More worryingly, if a bank were to at any point constitute more than 50% of the computing power on the network, it could in principle “manage” the currency by a combination of double spending and rejection of legitimate transactions. To this fear, two comforts may be offered. First, in historical situations where intermediaries were allowed most freely to compete, “there was no evidence of natural monopoly in [note] issue, nor even of a natural number of firms that could be called ‘small’” (White 1995, p. 146; cf. Selgin 1988, pp. 150ff). Nor in today’s economy is there evidence of such a tendency in deposit issue. Nevertheless, history also shows that incautious or malevolent regulation, especially if coordinated globally, might easily create a situation in which one reserve bank holds enough power to monopolize the blockchain’s computing power. Here, though, the ease with which new protocols can be created works as a safety valve. When the original protocol is attended with such disadvantages as a rogue reserve bank, dissatisfied users can always flock not only to a new bank, but to a new protocol. And if the rise of intermediation has by this point been accompanied by the development of an abstraction layer, the costs of switching will be very low indeed.

Alternatives to Intermediation

Intermediation will determine the value of base money more than vice versa. Thus Hayek (1979) notes,

[I]t is an erroneous belief that the value of gold or any metallic basis determines directly the value of money. The gold standard is a mechanism which was intended and for a long time did successfully force governments to control the quantity of money in an appropriate manner so as to keep its value equal with that of gold. But there are many historical instances which prove that it is certainly possible, if it is in the self-interest of the issuer, to control the quantity even of a token money in such a manner as to keep its value constant.

When the circulation of liabilities redeemable in base money comes to dwarf the circulation of the base money itself, the day-to-day demand for base money is low and stable compared to a pure commodity currency.19 If the main source of Bitcoin’s volatility is volatile demand, we can expect the issue and circulation of bitcoin-redeemable liabilities to stabilize the demand for (and therefore the value of) Bitcoin by allowing fluctuations to be borne by changes in the supply of liabilities rather than by the price level or the volume of transactions. The base money, on the other hand, influences the value of the liabilities only so far as redeemability (as, we presume, will be demanded of private intermediaries – cf. Selgin and White [1994]) disciplines issuers to maintain such a quantity of liabilities that the two values stay roughly on par.

The fact that redeemability does not determine value except so far as it determines quantity means that we might be able to design a protocol so that the total quantity of coins behaves similarly to a system of competitive and redeemable bank liabilities, without intermediation at all. Bitcoin’s periodic halving of the mining reward is arbitrary, and several alternative mining schemes have already been devised. Given the hurdles discussed earlier – at least some of which are likely to be permanently intractable – it will be worth considering alternatives by which the flexibility of intermediation might be baked into the protocol, thereby evading the legal hurdles.

One possibility is linking the proliferation of coins to some macroeconomic variable – for example unemployment or an exchange rate – as a central bank might target these variables. The relative ease with which new cryptocurrencies can be created might suggest a wide scope for experimentation here. However, as Sams (2015) puts it, “the variable will be a fact about the world outside of the system that needs to be represented inside the system via some trust-minimizing mechanism.”20 So far as this arrangement exposes the money supply to somebody’s will or to the interference of hostile or well-intentioned governments, it would not differ essentially from rule-based central banking: the rule can be broken, as it has been in every historical example.

The transactions velocity of money, however – VT in the equation of exchange – could be calculated endogenously. Coins exchanged per hour, reckoned either as a rolling or a cumulative-decay average, would be very close to the textbook definition, and would involve little more than a series of queries on the blockchain. We need not concern ourselves with the Sisyphean econometrics and data collection that central banks find necessary to guide their behavior, and without the financial sophistication we are trying to obviate, there is no worry about different velocities corresponding to M0, M1, etc.21 The only problem will be to set the optimal period over which the average is calculated. Too long and the monetary base will be rigid in supply; too short and M will fluctuate chaotically with transient changes in V.

Having a protocol-endogenous value for velocity would allow us to target MV at the protocol level, a money-supply norm with growing support (e.g. Selgin 1997; McCallum and Nelson 1998).22 Though in principle any behavior of the money stock is compatible with monetary equilibrium so long as it is perfectly anticipated and adjusted for in prices (Gilbert 1957), Selgin argues that an MV target will require the fewest discrete price adjustments, and for this reason is best suited to engender monetary equilibrium in a world where price adjustment is piecemeal and discontinuous.

Thus we set our sights on the elusive goal of a neutral money, one in which changes in the money supply cause no transient relative price changes. The problem will be to set the net rate of proliferation of coins (ΔM) to offset changes in velocity. This can be done easily enough by a protocol that provides both for the proliferation and deletion of coins,23 varying the rates of each to match the ΔM implied by the current measure of velocity, in a mechanism similar to the dynamic adjustment of Bitcoin’s hash target to computing power on the network.

I omit the details of implementation, however, because the focus on macroeconomic aggregates gets us in fact no closer to a solution. Such a scheme would be form without substance – a macroeconomic cargo cult, lacking the cardinal function of intermediation: the channeling of liquidity to its most valued uses. Intermediation ensures a relatively quick diffusion of new money through the economy – otherwise we are left with the transmission mechanism of the idiosyncratic spending habits of the miners to whom the new money goes as a reward. This will necessitate spurious and self-reversing price adjustments as miners spend their funds.

Such self-reversing price adjustments, of course, are equivalent with monetary disequilibrium; they vitiate completely the vaunted neutrality of our currency. Historically, equilibrating changes in the quantity of money have propagated through financial intermediaries. A currency which adjusts the quantity without intermediation, by contrast, highlights the fact that money approaches neutrality only when quantity changes are borne through a loanable funds market, and only to the extent of the depth of that market. Where changes in the quantity of money enter elsewhere than through a loanable funds market, transitional disequilibria will arise with greater severity, even if the quantity change is in the equilibrating direction.

A loanable funds market, where intermediaries can take bids from those most willing to bear those monetary changes, is more than a merely automatic act of channeling funds. Even if the protocol should also provide for a central clearinghouse to channel savings to those who might bid for it, individual to individual, the specialization and economies of scale that constitute the chief functional justification of banking as a separate industry are still lost. Individual entrepreneurs would scarcely be able to take on the administrative functions of an intermediary, and still less miners, who are by no means the same sort of person who would excel as an entrepreneur.

Intermediation, then – in particular, intermediation carried out by large-scale specialists – is not merely a means to achieve MV stability in pursuit of monetary equilibrium. Rather, intermediation appears to be necessary to take advantage of any benefits that MV stability ostensibly offers.

Decentral Banking?

Perhaps then, rather than mimicking the supply effects of intermediation at the protocol level, we could mimic intermediation itself at the protocol level – a “decentral bank” that oversees the distribution of ΔM to its most highly valued uses.

The first difficulty in replicating banking at the protocol level is that an automated system lacks the ability to evaluate the profitability of projects for which loans are to be made. Accordingly there exists a tradeoff between usefulness and vulnerability: the more impossible default becomes, the less useful intermediation becomes. The decentral bank can take measures to ensure repayment using auxiliary smart contracts, or (because the bank constitutes the protocol) enforce payment absolutely. But because risk is an inextricable part of any intertemporal transaction, it is unclear that automated intertemporal trade could, in conjunction with freedom of account creation, exist at all without commensurate vulnerability to exploitation. Control of balances can eliminate default risk to the bank, but beyond some margin, it can do this only by shifting the risk onto some other party, for example the recipients of borrowed funds, or to currency-holders as a whole.24

A more sophisticated scheme for the constitution of a decentral bank is what Sams (2015) calls “seigniorage shares”. In this scheme, the bank issues two distinct assets, coins and shares. The value of the coin is stabilized, and the value of the share floats. The protocol achieves its target ΔM by buying and issuing shares; something like automated open market operations. Shareholders broadcast the price at which they are willing to buy and sell shares, and the bank buys or issues a sufficient quantity to achieve the target ΔM.

The question, then, is: is this distribution sufficient to direct liquidity to its most valued uses in the same way as a banking system might? Seigniorage shares has obvious parallels with the structure of a private banking system. In the latter, a change in the demand for money registers directly to the issuing intermediaries as a drop in the gross volume of clearings, indicating that (for a given risk preference) the volume of loans, and therefore of issues, may be safely expanded. The bank distributes these new issues by lowering its interest rates, allowing marginal borrowers to take advantage of the new savings. Seigniorage shares in conjunction with endogenous MV stabilization would work similarly: a drop in the gross economy-wide volume of clearings signals the decentral bank to expand the volume of coins by some amount. The protocol buys shares, driving their value up (i.e. driving their expected yield down).

If we take shareholders to be the same as borrowers, the problem is solved and there is no obstacle in principle to the wholesale displacement of fiat currencies by stable cryptocurrencies. However, this assumption is dubious for several reasons. First of all, the establishment of firms in modern economies – especially highly innovative and highly risky ventures – are predicated on a division of labor between entrepreneurs (who borrow and allocate productive resources) and capitalists (who lend and bear risk). To equate the selling of shares with entrepreneurial borrowing is to merge the entrepreneur with the capitalist, for in order to “borrow”, the entrepreneur must already have shares to sell – i.e. capital funds – a significant impediment to the establishment of new enterprises. The entrepreneur may of course borrow funds in order to acquire shares, but this presupposes an existing financial market, which (if denominated in the cryptocurrency) obviates the whole project of endogenous stabilization, or (if denominated in another currency) does not minimize the dependence of the cryptocurrency on other, more established fiat currencies.

The relevance of this friction to the cryptocurrency’s volatility is an open question. If entrepreneurs are in fact little impeded by the necessity of being capitalists also, the solution is viable, and such a cryptocurrency faces only a network hurdle in displacing existing currencies. If the friction is a severe impediment to entrepreneurship, the savings implicit in increases in the demand for money (and vice versa) will tend to be maldistributed, necessitating self-reversing relative price changes and a loss of efficiency.

In the end, the same problem rears itself in both schemes: gratuitous or ad hoc credit creation is an irreducibly discretionary act, and on this act depend economic growth and the economical distribution of loanable funds. The volatility of today’s cryptocurrencies is merely symptomatic of this lack: creative solutions to the volatility problem that do not address the institutional hindrances to ad hoc credit creation will not allow them to sustain economic growth without relying on markets denominated in other currencies. Until such markets denominated in a cryptocurrency are established, the goal of displacing fiat currencies seems chimerical.

Conclusion

The very existence of cryptocurrency militates against any a priori declaration of a problem’s impossibility. Anonymous and trustless financial intermediation may turn out after all to be a technical problem with a clever solution. Nevertheless, so far as borrowing and lending entail risk – and thus moral hazard – it cannot be mitigated without personal judgment. Such judgment is difficult, if not impossible, to provide either 1) in an anonymous and trustless environment, or 2) automatically by a computer algorithm. Risk in this case is the obverse of trust, and a trustless protocol will be severely limited in dealing with it. This fact appears to put an upper limit on the financial sophistication a cryptocurrency can support without a supportive legal climate. As it is, true intermediation on a scale sufficient to stabilize the value of the currency will have to fight not only in the marketplace for general acceptance separately from the base money, but also in the political realm for the privilege of operating unmolested.

Of course, any opportunity for a cryptocurrency to suddenly supplant a national currency will likely coincide with the relaxation of restrictive regulations. In a political economy sense, it may be valuable to have a cryptocurrency with a stable purchasing power in order to allay fears of adoption, even if the currency would nevertheless not sustain widespread growth until the regulations preventing intermediation are relaxed. Nevertheless, as it stands now, though it would be an utterly quixotic task for governments to try to stamp out cryptocurrencies, they are well-positioned to prevent the emergence of stabilizing financial institutions around cryptocurrency ecosystems. Without these institutions, the hurdles cryptocurrencies face to supplanting more legally privileged and centrally issued currencies appear to be insurmountable.

Footnotes

  1. What follows is a brief account of the proof-of-work paradigm. For the sake of brevity, many technical details are elided. These are unimportant for the purposes of the paper, but can be found in Nakamoto (2008). The details of the less common proof-of-stake paradigm (King & Nadal 2012) are somewhat different, but the security implications are largely similar. The economic implications are discussed in subsequent sections.
  2. The marginal benefit of mining will include expectations of the cryptocurrency’s future price, so when its value is expected to rise, the electricity costs can exceed the value of the coins mined. That this comes to a very large amount of electricity is illustrated by the 2011 police raid of a Canadian Bitcoin miner’s home because his energy usage was consistent with the high-powered lamps used for growing marijuana.
  3. Starting with a reward of 50 coins per block, the supply path is described by the infinite sum Σ(210,000 × 50/2i), which comes to 21 million. Because the hash target adjusts to keep the time between verified blocks more or less constant, each period i is about four years.
  4. This is known as a 51% attack. While no attack has so far ever been successfully executed, the potential – at least for Bitcoin – is a matter of some debate. Dowd & Hutchinson (2015) argue that Bitcoin’s mining algorithm is characterized by significant economies of scale, due to the fact that the cryptographic problem can be more efficiently solved by specialized GPU-based machines known as ASICs (Application Specific Integrated Circuits). In addition, because it is common for miners to join a “pool” to decrease the variance of their returns, the argument is that a malicious pool operator would be in a better position to pull off an attack. In 2014, many users abandoned the Ghash.io pool to prevent it from reaching 51% of the computing power on the network. Thus, the very publicity of the problem seems to have stymied it. Ghash responded by implementing measures to lower its own share. But if a competitive solution is not satisfactory, there are technical solutions as well. Other cryptocurrencies (Litecoin, for example) implement a modified proof of work function that significantly diminishes the potential economies of scale to mining. Others, using proof-of-stake, dispense with arbitrarily intensive computation entirely.
  5. This is analogous to the discussion in Selgin (1988, pp. 42ff) in which even minimal note-brand discrimination will prevent undue credit expansion by any single competitive note-issuing bank. Cf. also White (2014).
  6. Crypto-currencies could become much closer substitutes to one another if intermediation were to arise with the help of an abstraction layer through which various protocols can be treated similarly by buyers and sellers. This possibility is discussed below.
  7. An update that allowed for the issue of new bitcoins beyond the 21 million limit would require changes to what clients consider to be valid blocks. Such backward-incompatible updates (or “hard forks”) have in fact been issued several times over the course of Bitcoin’s history, though not entirely smoothly. As the 2016 block size controversy shows, hard forks in practice require something close to unanimous consent from the community. Given the importance that existing users attach to a non-inflationary currency, any attempt to fudge the 21 million limit would in all likelihood fail to be adopted on a sufficiently wide scale. For this reason, if competition should indeed select for a more expansionary protocol, it will almost certainly be something other than Bitcoin. Even if the team did succeed in pushing the update, however, it would still be unable to collect seigniorage from the expansion without further changes involving the rewards to mining.
  8. The hash target adjusts about every two weeks (more precisely, every 2,016 blocks) based on the time taken since the previous adjustment, so sudden changes in computing power on the network can have transient effects on the rate of coin generation.
  9. Discussion at the level of the protocol makes total transactions, T, more appropriate (and, conveniently, more measurable) than sales of final goods and services, y. V will then refer to the more expansive transactions velocity VT rather than income velocity Vy.
  10. For currencies on the gold standard, the “gold bands” served as a credible focal point beyond which speculators would not ordinarily let the currency’s exchange rate move (Bordo & MacDonald 2012). Engel and Frankel (1984) also find evidence that the U.S. was able to take advantage of this sort of speculation during the Federal Reserve’s brief stint with money supply targeting: increases in M1 were actually associated with appreciation of the dollar, indicating a consensus expectation of compensating contraction in the future.
  11. White (2014), however, notes that Bitcoin does serve as a vehicle currency for altcoin exchanges, most of which likely suffer from even more severe volatility than Bitcoin.
  12. It is true that fluctuations the price of gold did sometimes spur prospecting and more intensive output from gold mines, but this effect was both unpredictable and slow. Bordo (1984, p. 218 fn) finds the strongest supply response to deviations from the purchasing power trend of gold at a lag of 16 years. Likewise, a jump in the price of Bitcoins brings more computing power to bear on the network, but because of the adjustable hash target, this affects only the distribution of coins, not the long-term rate of coin generation. Although these responses are in the equilibrating direction, they are both practically useless for the short-term fluctuations with which we are here concerned.
  13. Three notes on this point: 1) Metals could be minted from nonmonetary uses, but I will consider this to be a medium- to long-run phenomenon. 2) I ignore the problem of debasement except to note that this is an aspect where cryptocurrencies are more resilient to political exigencies than are precious metals. 3) Credit did exist, but private liabilities did not circulate as money prior to the spread of banking institutions, and could not therefore contribute to the elasticity of the money supply (White 1999, p. 12).
  14. See Selgin (1988) for a theoretical account of the mechanics of supply adjustment through fractional reserve banking under a gold standard. Where this process was impeded, periodic crashes were the rule – see also Selgin (2010, p. 494) for a suggestive graph comparing the responsiveness of US and Canadian money supply to money demand. It is nonetheless a testament to the salutary effects of financial development that, impeded as it was in various ways in different places, it was able to set off a historically unprecedented explosion in economic growth throughout Europe and North America.
  15. For the sake of concision, I will refer hereafter to bank liabilities in general, including checkable deposits, simply as banknotes. Though the two gain different macroeconomic significance under a central banking regime where banknotes are base money, we are analyzing a hypothetical crypto-banking system as a free-banking regime in which movement from one to the other has no macroeconomically significant effects (cf. Selgin 1988, ch. 8).
  16. This means the network effects impeding Bitcoin’s adoption described in Luther (2015) are likely understated.
  17. Adding parameters to coins would allow at best the establishment of a 100% reserve bank, which is somewhat the idea behind Open Transactions’ voting pools.
  18. A blockchain is essentially a decentralized database, so multiple protocols can operate side by side on the same blockchain if they speak a sufficiently similar language. This allows smaller enterprises to take advantage of the volume of mining done on Bitcoin’s blockchain. By itself, this does not diminish the hurdle of protocol incompatibility. However, see below on Open Transactions as an abstraction layer.
  19. Note, on the other hand, the dramatic increase in the volatility of the purchasing power of gold following its final demonetization at the collapse of the Bretton Woods system (Erb and Harvey 2013).
  20. The Ethereum white paper makes an interesting proposal to use a decentralized data feed for this purpose. This feed would guarantee accuracy in a manner similar to a prediction market, by rewarding all entries within the 25th and 75th percentile – the assumption being that the true value is a natural focal point, and the median entry will be a reliable estimate. This is certainly a more robust solution than simply trusting a single data source. Still (as Sams notes), skewing the focal point will be much easier than an analogous 51% attack on a cryptocurrency’s blockchain, especially if the source of the data is a single agency.
  21. Off-chain transactions (i.e. Bitcoin derivatives) do exist, which might indicate a rudimentary financial market. Nevertheless, I am not aware of any evidence that such derivatives circulate as currency, which is the important aspect for stabilizing the demand for base money.
  22. McCallum and Nelson actually advocate an NGDP target, which differs from our MV target only in practical considerations of measurement: 1) using the narrower income velocity Vy rather than transactions velocity VT, and 2) using the other side of the equation of exchange (Py) as the target. Selgin (2015) suggests the possibility of an NGDP-targeting cryptocurrency, but does not go into any technical details. A price level target (as advocated by, for example, Sams [2015]) would require the same data-feed apparatus as targeting other external variables: the protocol can calculate the product PT endogenously (because it equals MV), but calculating a value of T in order to separate out a targetable value of P would require the construction of a price index – a difficult task without an existing taxation apparatus, and fraught with the same specification and measurement issues that come with the construction of any other price index.
  23. Peercoin, for example, takes Bitcoin’s variable transaction fee and makes it a mandatory, fixed amount, which is then destroyed rather than going to the miner. Alternatively, a rate of nominal depreciation could be built into the protocol, amounting to something like a continuously stamped Gesell currency, as discussed by Keynes (1936, ch. 23, §VI).
  24. Derivatives such as futures contracts do exist as smart contracts or multi-signature transactions, but (as noted earlier) they do not circulate as currency, and they do not entail any default risk: the coins at stake are held in escrow until a trusted party verifies the state of the world specified in the futures contract. The protocol itself, of course, should ideally be trustless. It is no more capable of verifying the trustworthiness of third party adjudicators than it is of the original borrower.

Topics

BankingBlockchainCryptocurrencyFree bankingMacroeconomicsMonetary PolicyMoneyF.A. HayekGeorge SelginJeffrey FrankelKevin DowdLawrence WhiteLeland YeagerLudwig Von MisesMilton Friedman

SHARE

Facebook Twitter Reddit Threads

8 Comments

  • 1

    cx

    Jun 08, 2011 at 18:26 | Reply

    Bitcoins are specie. They are things desired in and of themselves. We have so much mental baggage in the way that we try to categorize money (token, commodity, fiat,..) that it becomes hard to recognize things like bitcoins that challenge our initial assumptions (digital is token, hard is commodity).

    Bitcoins are a particular use pattern of numbers that emerge from the use of a cryptographic framework (Bitcoin). They are not tokens or symbols of something else. They are discreet entities with cryptographic rather than physical boundaries.

    I think both men would have ultimately welcomed Bitcoin. Rothbard especially so because of what it may foreshadow for the state.

    • 1.1

      Cameron Harwick

      Jun 08, 2011 at 19:16

      If you mean that the distinction between token and specie is “specious” (har har), then absolutely. If the subjective theory of value means anything, then “cryptographic electronic signature” is not inherently less valuable than “ooh, it’s shiny”. The important thing is just that it’s hard to create more.

      You’re absolutely right that there’s no reason Bitcoins couldn’t be used economically in exactly the same way as gold. If government pressure eases to the point where we can get stable formal institutions around it, I’ll predict fractional-reserve banks which issue their own “Bitcoin-backed” currency. This would operate along the lines of Selgin’s free-banking theory, and would provide a measure of price stability for prices in that currency, even if Bitcoins themselves remain deflationary. Bitcoin itself I would imagine then being used mainly for reserves, for the same reasons that banknotes eventually superseded gold coins in daily use (not just because they’re easier to carry). And considering all the hoarding worries around Bitcoin, it should be a relatively small leap from major hoarder to moneylender, and then bank.

      You may be right about Rothbard welcoming Bitcoin. But his followers at least, from what I’ve seen, have been pretty down on the idea. Mental baggage sounds about right, hah.

  • 2

    MoonShadow

    Jun 08, 2011 at 19:39 | Reply

    It’s good to see that some Austrians are taking the rise of Bitcoin seriously. This is a fine article on the subject, and that is saying a lot since so many of your peers are filling the Internet with rushed Bitcoin commentaries littered with error.

  • 3

    Matt

    Jun 09, 2011 at 0:38 | Reply

    “it wouldn’t be very fair to fault any mid-century economist for failing to predict its possibility”

    True we can’t fault them for not predicting Bitcoin. However Bitcoin isn’t that different from a pure decentralized peer-to-peer system of valuing and trading rocks for example is it? The one distinction is that the inflation of Bitcoins are definitely capped at 21.

    Bitcoin is technically a more advanced currency, but in principle doesn’t seem that different than anything Rothbard or Hayek had seen historically.

    Am I wrong?

    • 3.1

      Cameron Harwick

      Jun 09, 2011 at 16:22

      You’re right, economically it should behave similarly to gold. As far as this is true, all their insights should remain valid. But it has other unique features as well, especially as regard politics, which would definitely influence the path we take towards a free market in money (which they both wrote about). Rothbard’s insistence that we need a gold dollar, for example, is looking less and less relevant as the dollar itself becomes less and less relevant.

      The main difference is, gold is easy to monopolize, and has few alternatives (silver? copper?). There can exist any number of equally good cryptocurrencies, however, and this is the practical strength of the idea. Particular cryptocurrencies can be monopolized, but it’s very simple to just use a different, more or less identical one. They can spring up faster than they can be monopolized.

      So yeah, it’s a new form, perhaps more general, which still conforms to old economic laws, but has very different political implications.

  • 4

    irdial

    Jun 25, 2011 at 4:52 | Reply

    Thank you for this great article.

    At last, someone with in depth knowledge about Austrian School Economics is taking Bitcoin seriously and approaching it with rigour and references to theory.

    This article also goes some way to explain why some ‘Rothbardians’ have been so reflexively hostile to the idea of Bitcoin.

    Bitcoin really is the best current option in the fight to destroy the State’s monopoly on money, and everyone should adopt it, even on the scale of a few tens of dollars, for that reason alone.

    If all the hundreds of millions of disaffected people out there all put $20 into buying a bitcoin, and ran the client full time the networks worth and integrity would be strengthened to a level that would put it way beyond the reach of the State, and any lie its media outlets tried to spread about it.

  • 5

    Jon Matonis

    Jun 26, 2011 at 11:59 | Reply

    Great focus on bitcoin from an Austrian economist. I particularly like your comment above about the subjective theory of value in relation to a cryptographic math puzzle versus a shiny element atomic number 79. It seems to me that both would have the same value on a deserted island.

  • 6

    Lorenzo from Oz

    Nov 04, 2017 at 17:39 | Reply

    I found this recent open letter very clarifying when it came to the crypto-assets.
    https://blog.chain.com/a-letter-to-jamie-dimon-de89d417cb80

Leave a Reply

More Content